

Effect of antitrust on innovative development with a different degree of intellectual property protection
https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2022-9-93-108
Abstract
Intellectual property is often referred to as a “legal monopoly”, which should stimulate the innovative activity of authors and inventors. In this formulation, increased antitrust regulation should always have a negative effect on the innovation industry, since it is aimed at reducing the companies’ profits, and therefore, other things being equal, reducing the innovation incentives. The paper reveals the conditions under which this statement can be true, and under which, on the contrary, the strengthening of antimonopoly regulation leads to an increase in innovative output. Using cross-country data, an empirical assessment of the mutual influence of the effectiveness of antimonopoly regulation and the degree of protection of intellectual property rights on the efficiency of the innovation sector and the economy are obtained. As an indicator of relative efficiency the paper considers the proximity to the production possibilities frontier, determined by the stochastic frontier analysis (SFA) method. As a result, the hypothesis for the complementary nature of the influence of both policies is confirmed: the strengthening of one gives a positive result only when the other is strong. The complementary nature of policies can be related to the following aspects. In the context of weak IP right protection, right holders are extensively using alternative mechanisms for the specification of property rights, which includes business practices that are controversial from the antitrust point of view. In such a case, strengthening the severity of antimonopoly regulation increases the costs of such practices and ultimately reduces the effectiveness of the intellectual property protection reducing output in the innovation industry. This result justifies the existence of exceptions for the IP owners, which could be present in the antimonopoly legislation in countries with a low level of IP rights protection. But as the effectiveness of the IP rights protection becomes stronger, such exceptions can be canceled. This result also shows that the notion of IP as a “legal monopoly” is overly simplistic and can lead to risks of Type I enforcement errors (punishing the innocent).
About the Author
A. N. MorozovRussian Federation
Anton N. Morozov
Moscow
References
1. Volkov A. Y., Radchenko T. A., Bannikova (Sukhorukova) K. A. (2019a). Localization investment and opportunities for legalization of parallel import in Russia. Ekonomicheskaya Politika, Vol. 14, No. 1, pp. 54—75. (In Russian). https://doi.org/10.18288/1994-5124-2019-1-54-75
2. Volkov A. Y., Radchenko T. A., Bannikova (Sukhorukova) K. A. (2019b). Parallel imports in Russia: Areas for protection, risk, development. EKO, No. 1, pp. 153—167. (In Russian).
3. Kurdin A. A., Shastitko A. E. (2017). Two arguments for a limitation of antitrust for IPR-related deals in emerging market economies. Voprosy Gosudarstvennogo i Municipalnogo Upravleniya, Vol. 1, pp. 31—49. (In Russian).
4. Polterovich V. M. (2016). Institutions of catching-up development (on the project of a new model for economic development of Russia). Economic and Social Changes: Facts, Trends, Forecast, No. 5, pp. 34—56. (In Russian). https://doi.org/10.15838/esc.2016.5.47.2
5. Shastitko A. (2013). Is it worth to protect competition from intellectual property rights? Voprosy Ekonomiki, No. 8, pp. 60—82. (In Russian). https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2013-8-60-82
6. Shastitko A. E., Kurdin A. A. (2014). Protection of intellectual property rights and competition policy: Seeking for a better balance. Journal of the New Economic Association, Vol. 1, No. 21, pp. 111—135. (In Russian).
7. Shastitko A. E., Kurdin A. A. (2015). Opportunities and risks of antitrust reform in the area of intellectual property rights relations. Nauchnye Issledovaniya Ekonomicheskogo Fakulteta, Vol. 7, No. 1, pp. 5—31. (In Russian).
8. Acemoglu D., Akcigit U. (2012). Intellectual property rights policy, competition and innovation. Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 10, No. 1, pp. 1—42. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1542-4774.2011.01053.x
9. Apostolopoulos H. (2007). Refusal-to-deal cases of ip rights in the aftermarket of US and EU law: Convergence of both law systems through speaking the same language of law and economics. DePaul Business and Commercial Law Journal, Vol. 5, No. 2, article 3.
10. Banerjee D. (2003). Software piracy: A strategic analysis and policy instruments. International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 21, No. 1, pp. 97—127. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-7187(01)00090-X
11. Baten J., Bianchi N., Moser P. (2017). Compulsory licensing and innovation — Historical evidence from German patents after WWI. Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 126, pp. 231—242. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2017.01.002
12. Belleflamme P., Picard P. M. (2007). Piracy and competition. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Vol. 16, No. 2, pp. 351—383. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1530-9134.2007.00142.x
13. Chatterjee C., Kubo K., Pingali V. (2015). The consumer welfare implications of governmental policies and firm strategy in markets for medicines. Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 44, pp. 255—273. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2015.09.001
14. Chen Y. (2014). Refusal to deal, intellectual property rights, and antitrust. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, Vol. 30, No. 3, pp. 533—557. https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewt004
15. Chen Y. J., Seshadri S. (2007). Product development and pricing strategy for information goods under heterogeneous outside opportunities. Information Systems Research, Vol. 18, No. 2, pp. 150—172. https://doi.org/10.1287/isre.1070.0119
16. Clemons E. K., Madhani N. (2010). Regulation of digital businesses with natural monopolies or third-party payment business models: Antitrust lessons from the analysis of Google. Journal of Management Information Systems, Vol. 27, No. 3, pp. 43—80. https://doi.org/10.2753/MIS0742-1222270303
17. Davis P., Garcés E. (2009). Quantitative techniques for competition and antitrust analysis. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
18. Encaoua D., Hollander A. (2002). Competition policy and innovation. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 18, No. 1, pp. 63—79. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxrep/18.1.63
19. Feenstra R. C., Inklaar R., Timmer M. P. (2015). The next generation of the Penn World Table. American Economic Review, Vol. 105, No. 10, pp. 3150—3182. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20130954
20. Jones J. C. H., Potashnik T., Zhang A. (2001). Patents, brand-generic competition and the pricing of ethical drugs in Canada: Some empirical evidence from British Columbia, 1981—1994. Applied Economics, Vol. 33, No. 7, pp. 947—956. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036840121705
21. Karjala D. S. (1999). Copyright protection of operating software, copyright misuse, and antitrust. Cornell Journal of Law and Public Policy, Vol. 9, No. 1, pp. 161—192.
22. Lemley M. A. (1990). The economic irrationality of the patent misuse doctrine. California Law Review, Vol. 78, No. 6, pр. 1599—1632. https://doi.org/10.2307/3480805
23. Ma T.-C. (2011). The effect of competition law enforcement on economic growth. Journal of Competition Law & Economics, Vol. 7, No. 2, pp. 301—334. https://doi.org/10.1093/joclec/nhq032
24. Ma T.-C. (2012). Legal tradition and antitrust effectiveness. Empirical Economics, Vol. 43, No. 3, pp. 1263—1297. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-011-0517-5
25. Ménière F., Lévêque Y. (2004). The economics of patents and copyright. Berkeley Electronic Press.
26. Moser P., Voena A. (2012). Compulsory licensing: Evidence from the trading with the enemy act. American Economic Review, Vol. 102, No. 1, pp. 396—427. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.102.1.396
27. Nicholson M. W. (2008). An antitrust law index for empirical analysis of international competition policy. Journal of Competition Law & Economics, Vol. 4, No. 4, pp. 1009—1029. https://doi.org/10.1093/joclec/nhn009
28. Pate R. H. (2003). Antitrust and intellectual property. Address at the American Intellectual Property Law Association, Mid-Winter Institute, January 24.
29. Posner R. A. (2005). Intellectual property: The law and economics approach. Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 19, No. 2, pp. 57—73. https://doi.org/10.1257/0895330054048704
30. Scherer F. M., Watal J. (2002). Post-TRIPS options for access to patented medicines in developing nations. Journal of International Economic Law, Vol. 5, No. 4, pp. 913—939. https://doi.org/10.1093/jiel/5.4.913
31. Seifert J. (2015). Welfare effects of compulsory licensing. Journal of Regulatory Economics, Vol. 48, No. 3, pp. 317—350. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-015-9288-9
32. Shapiro D. M., Switzer L. N. (1993). The stock market response to changing drug patent legislation: The case of compulsory licensing in Canada. Managerial and Decision Economics, Vol. 14, No. 3, pp. 247—259. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.4090140305
33. U.S. Department of Justice, Fed. Trade Commission (2007). Antitrust enforcement and intellectual property rights: Promoting innovation and competition. Washington, DC.
Supplementary files
Review
For citations:
Morozov A.N. Effect of antitrust on innovative development with a different degree of intellectual property protection. Voprosy Ekonomiki. 2022;(9):93-108. (In Russ.) https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2022-9-93-108